Economic Growth: The Role of Human Capital
On November 10, Christopher Pissarides, Nobel Prize laureate in Economics and Professor at the London School of Economics, spoke at HSE ICEF. His lecture on human capital and its impact on economic growth commemorated the 20th anniversary of ICEF.
Professor Pissarides is a renowned expert in labour economics, macroeconomic policy, growth economics and structural change. Human capital undoubtedly impacts the development of the labour market and the economy as a whole, but, as Prof. Pissarides demonstrated, it is difficult to accurately measure its contribution. Furthermore, the impact of human capital isn’t always positive, depending largely upon how the population puts it skills and knowledge to use.
How is human capital defined?
Human capital is defined by the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) as the knowledge, skills, competencies and attributes embodied in individuals. It is acquired through formal learning, substantiated by school and university certificates, as well as through non-certified means (such as accumulation of knowledge through work experience).
The consensus is that both kinds of human capital, that is, education and training, contribute to growth, in particular by means of productivity gains. But this effect is very difficult to measure. According to Prof. Pissarides, ‘countless macro empirical studies have failed to establish a precise and robust relationship between human capital and GDP growth’. Estimates at the aggregate level suggest a considerable range of impact: if, on average, the stock of education is increased by one year of schooling, per capita GDP grows by 3-15%.
Why does this happen? What’s important is not only human capital itself, but the way it is used by humans. Its contribution to the economy depends on the incentives that the person has to use it productively, and these incentives vary.
How is human capital used?
Incentives to use human capital to contribute to productivity are largely determined by the institutional structure of the economy. However, institutions vary widely between countries, so it cannot be measured easily.
Some institutions might offer incentives for ‘rent seeking’, whereby many individuals are involved in redistribution without new production, instead of productivity enhancement. For example, corruption in the public sector, complex taxation laws and lack of intellectual property protection are incentives for highly trained people to enter the public sector to extract bribes or to become lawyers to make profit from endless court disputes, rather than to contribute to productivity.
Excess market monopolization promotes similar behavior. This can be observed in the oil and gas sector, however suppression of competition is also common among non-manufacturing businesses in market economies. Prof. Pissarides gave the example of the transportation technology company, Uber. In some areas where Uber operates, local authorities are earning huge money selling licenses to a small number of taxi drivers. In this way, Uber is being forced out of many European and American cities.
Such institutional ‘tension’ usually limits the contribution of human capital to GDP growth, but not its contribution to the growth of private revenues. Such cases occur, where an increase in personal wealth doesn’t lead to the growth of public wealth.
Since education systems and economy levels vary from country to country, the return on investment in human capital also varies. Empirical studies have shown that countries lagging behind the technological frontier, such as many of the African nations, grow by applying simple technologies learned from other countries. Based on this approach, development of elementary education would be their most effective strategy for economic growth. Populations in middle income countries acquire more sophisticated technologies; hence, investment in higher education by these countries would be most effective. In frontier countries, university education is most beneficial for economic growth.
When does human capital become firm capital?
For a given macro environment, human capital is most productive when a firm provides the right incentives to operate in productivity-enhancing activities. The firms that succeed in organizing their internal structure in such a way so as to ensure maximum efficiency of their employees will experience the most growth. This can be referred to as ‘organizational capital’; the effectiveness of which is related to ‘managerial capital’, or the ability of the company managers to administer the company properly.
A successful firm can be considered a monopolist in what it does, not as a result of barriers it creates for others, but as a result of its way of organizing itself in order to gain an implicit competitive advantage. Prof. Pissarides compared firms to football teams. Many teams have talented players. But not all of them are able (and the role of the manager, or coach, is vital here) to find a place on the field as part of the configuration which will lead to a win for the team.
Is it possible to imitate the winning strategies of other ‘teams’ (firms)? Yes, but only to a certain extent. Human capital is at its most effective when it exploits the unique characteristics of each individual, and not when it copies the characteristics of others. The ability of individuals to work together and to exchange ideas and concepts is transformed into social capital. The sum of individual human capital, social capital and the organizational capital of firms equals the intellectual capital of firms, and, ultimately, countries.
See also:
Human Capital Multidisciplinary Research Centre Opens Exhibition at Technoprom 2023 Forum
On August 22, 2023, the Human Capital Multidisciplinary Research Centre (HCMRC) opened an exhibition as part of the Technoprom 2023 forum in Novosibirsk. On the opening day, more than 300 people visited the stand, of which more than 50 took part in an interactive ‘anthropologist simulator’ and a visual attention test. The HSE News Service reports on the exposition and the feedback received by the experts.
Human Capital Multidisciplinary Research Centre Presents Results to International Supervisory Board
The Human Capital Multidisciplinary Research Centre, established in 2020 and coordinated by HSE University, recently held a session of the International Supervisory Board and presented work results for the period of 2020-2022 along with plans for 2023-2025, including fundamental and applied research in the field of human development, creation of unique empirical databases for the development of evidence-based social and economic policies, and the introduction of digital approaches in humanities and social sciences.
HSE University Studies Human Capital as Part of Consortium
The Human Capital Interdisciplinary Research Centre (HCIRC) is a world-class research centre comprising a consortium of HSE University, RANEPA, MGIMO University, and the Institute of Ethnology and Anthropology of the Russian Academy of Sciences (RAS). Its work was highly rated by the RAS in 2021. Lilia Ovcharova, HSE University Vice Rector and initiator of the centre’s creation, talked to the HSE News Service about integration in international studies on active ageing, creating a database on development trends in human potential, studying the effects of digitalisation, and the centre’s priority activities for the future.
HSE University and Consortium Partners Aim to Take Human Capital Studies to New Level
On January 14, at the 2021 Gaidar Forum, which was held at the Russian Presidential Academy of National Economy and Public Administration (RANEPA), HSE University Rector Yaroslav Kuzminov and leaders of three other institutions signed an agreement to establish the Human Capital Multidisciplinary Research Center (HCMRC). The other co-signers were RANEPA Rector Vladimir Mau, MGIMO University Rector Anatoly Torkunov, and Dmitry Funk, Director of the N.N. Miklukho-Maclay Institute of Ethnology and Anthropology of the Russian Academy of Sciences. The Center will focus on that key areas of human capital studies that are of current global importance.
‘Cognitive Skills Are not Sufficient to Be Successful in Labour Market’
This September, HSE – St. Petersburg hosted the 3rd IZA/HSE University Workshop on Skills and Preferences and Labor Market Outcomes in Post-Transition and Emerging Economies. HSE News Service spoke with Professor Lehmann, co-organizer of the workshop, about human capital, the importance of cognitive and noncognitive skills, and the challenges empirical labour economists encounter when studying these issues in post-transition and emerging economies.
HSE to Focus on Applied Research of Human Capital
In order to research human capital, Lilia Ovcharova, a renowned scholar and expert on social policy, has been appointed Vice Rector responsible for applied human capital research at HSE. Human capital development studies are key priority for our university.
Russia Has the Resources for a Budget Manoeuvre That Helps Education, Healthcare, and Social Welfare
Issues concerning changes pertinent to key social spheres were discussed during the ‘Human Capital and Social Policy’ plenary session of the XIX April International Academic Conference on Economic and Social Development.
'Human Capital, Quality of Life and Infrastructure around Cities Should Be the New Areas for Investment' Says Yaroslav Kuzminov
On the 28th February at a plenary session of the economic forum in Krasnodar 'New sources of growth for Russia' attended by deputy PM Arkady Dvorkovich and ex-minister of finance Aleksei Kudrin, HSE Rector Yaroslav Kuzminov set out three important sources of economic growth. This article presents the main points of his address.
There is a Growing Demand for Good Social Infrastructure
‘Private investment is ready to enter the social sphere – if supported by the state them,’ said Yaroslav Kuzminov, HSE Rector, at ‘Russia Calling’, an investment forum organized by VTB Capital.